Markets and the ACA: Why the Supreme Court Will Uphold the ACA
by Beverly Mann
The link to the ACA litigation blog article I discuss is here .
‘Markets’ and the ACA: Why the Supreme Court Will Uphold the ACA
In my post last week about the activity/inactivity canard on which the challengers to the constitutionality of the ACA claim, I wrote:
In his [blog] post, [high-profile rightwing law professor Randy] Barnett pointed out something that was not in the other reports I’d read about [last month’s oral arguments in the 4th Circuit Court of Appeals]: that in a lengthy exchange with [acting Solicitor General Neal] Katyal, [Judge Diana Gribbon] Motz indicated that she buys the activity/non-activity distinction, because she believes the definition of the word “regulate” means “regulate activity.” She kept insisting that if the failure to buy health insurance is inactivity rather than activity, then, under her understanding of the definition of the word “regulate,” Congress couldn’t regulate it.
Katyal flubbed the response to this. Partly. He noted the Supreme Court’s most recent relevant Commerce Clause/Necessary and Proper Clause decision, Gonzales v. Raich, a 2005 opinion that held that the federal statute enacted under the Commerce Clause powers that criminalizes the growing and use of marijuana applies even to homegrown marijuana that is not sold even intrastate, much less in interstate commerce, and that is just for the personal use of the grower. The rationale: that even those actions impact the interstate market for marijuana. Since the Commerce Clause gives Congress the authority to regulate interstate markets, Congress can, under the Necessary and Proper Clause, regulate things that otherwise cannot be regulated under the Commerce power if those things impact the interstate market.Motz, though, missed the point. Growing marijuana is an activity, she pointed out, so how is Raich relevant to whether Congress can, under the Commerce Clause together with the Necessary and Proper Clause, regulate inactivity, she wanted to know? Well, um, maybe that what’s relevant isn’t the particular reason why the Commerce Clause alone isn’t enough and must be aided by the Necessary and Proper Clause, but instead that if something—whether activity only within a state’s boundary, or instead inactivity, or instead whatever—impacts a market that Congress has the power under the Commerce Clause to regulate, then Congress has the constitutional authority to regulate it as necessary and proper under the Commerce Clause.
Katyal apparently was too dumbfounded to explain this.
The Commerce Clause gives Congress the power, in the Constitution’s precise words, “To regulate Commerce with foreign Nations, and among the several States, and with the Indian Tribes.” It’s one of the “enumerated,” or specified, powers that the Constitution gives Congress, and which the Necessary and Proper Clause augments.
Last Thursday, Santa Clara U. law professor Brad Joondeph, who has a blog called “aca litigation blog,” wrote trenchantly as the opening paragraph of a lengthy post titled “The regulated activity”:
Much ink has been spilled over whether Congress–using its commerce power alone, or its commerce power in conjunction with the Necessary and Proper Clause–has the authority to regulate “inactivity.” But there is a logically prior question–a question that is often quite tricky in enumerated powers cases–that must be resolved before reaching the inactivity issue. Namely, one has to define exactly what conduct Congress is regulating in the challenged provision.
[A] critical question that every judge must confront (or at least every judge reaching the merits) is whether the minimum coverage provision (a) regulates conduct in the health insurance market (as the challengers contend), or (b) regulates conduct in the health care services market (as the United States maintains).
In a direct and immediate sense, of course, the individual mandate regulates behavior in the insurance market. But one can easily argue (as with §4306 above) that what it really regulates is the payment for services in the health care service market. Sure, the provision, when examined in isolation, only directly concerns the purchase of health insurance. But the broader scheme, taken as a whole, shows that what Congress was actually regulating–of which the individual mandate is only a part–is the financing of health care services. Congress logically cared whether people carry health coverage not for its own sake, but due to its implications for the financing of services in the health care market, the ultimate object of its regulation.
So which is it? Which market does the minimum coverage provision actually regulate?
The larger point, he says, is that
the relevant “regulated activity”—or, phrased differently, the relevant regulated market—is quite open to debate [and that the] fact that the challenged provision only regulates a particular activity directly (… the decision whether to acquire health insurance in the case of the ACA) does not answer the question. The regulated activity or market, for purposes of evaluating whether the challenged provision is within Congress’s enumerated powers, may well be different than the conduct that the provision directly governs. Answering the critical question is not as simple as examining the empirical realities of the challenged provision by itself.
He’s spot-on. But I think it would be profoundly disingenuous for any judge to say that the relevant market is simply the health insurance market. The purpose and the effect of the ACA, including the mandate provision, clearly is to regulate the method by which healthcare is funded in this country.
Joohdeph ends his post by saying that the distinction between regulation of the market for health insurance and regulation of the market for healthcare is “obviously of enormous importance.” He writes:
For if the relevant market is only that for health insurance, the minimum coverage requirement looks truly unprecedented (and constitutionally problematic). But if the relevant market is that for health care services, then what Congress is regulating is a market in which virtually every American activelyparticipates–and the minimum coverage provision is merely regulating the commercial terms on which thatactive participation occurs. And this framing, of course, makes it seem well within Congress’s authority to regulate interstate commerce.
He’s right, but only if, as he says earlier, the market for health insurance is defined so narrowly that health insurance is viewed as a commodity, a product, independent of the product’s purpose and effect. In the same way, some argue that platforms like online casino paypal blur the lines between entertainment and financial risk, treating them merely as commodities without addressing the potential consequences for consumer protection. And then, the constitutional issue would not, I think, be whether Congress has the authority under the Commerce Clause, aided by the Necessary and Proper Clause, to regulate the health insurance market, but instead whether this violates some other constitutional limitation. You know: the slippery-slope-to-government-compelled-consumption-of-broccoli argument.
Ultimately, the Supreme Court is unlikely, in my opinion, to say that the relevant market is health insurance rather than healthcare. That would pretty much require them to do what they did in Bush v. Gore: pronounce the ruling good for that case only. Which is why I think the ACA will survive the constitutional challenge. But if it doesn’t, it’s likely to be one a 5-4 slippery-slope-to-government-compelled-consumption-of-broccoli ruling.
—-
The most important of the ACA-case appellate arguments is tomorrow afternoon in Atlanta, at the 11th Circuit Court of Appeals. This is the appeal in the case in which 26 states and one private organization are the plaintiffs, and in which the trial-level judge, Roger Vinson, held the entire ACA unconstitutional because, he said, the mandate is too essential to the entire statute to strike that provision down without also striking down the entire ACA. Paul Clement, who, it was announced today, will be representing Arizona in defending the constitutionality of the most draconian of Arizona’s recently enacted immigration-law statutes, and who is representing six Republican House members in defending the constitutionality of the Defense of Marriage Act, is the states’ lead attorney. (Looks like a pattern here, for Clement.)
Hmm. It never occurred to me that buying health insurance was buying a commodity. I was thinking of it as a means of payment for the medical services I need. It’s hard to see how one can be separated from the other since we have a largely fee for service system. I can’t see how there is any inactivity on the part of an uninsured person. He is actively requiring other people to pay for his medical care at some point in his life. You can’t call it cost-shifting without using a transitive verb after all, can you? NancyO
I was thinking of it as a means of payment for the medical services I need.
Not directed specifically at you, but this is part of the problem with the nomenclature of “health insurance”, when in practice it functions as a pre-paid expenditure plan.
Separately, having “health insurance” does not guarantee access to healthcare, whether that insurance is provided by a private organization or a government entity.
Besides, Raich was a horrible decision – akin to the regulation of my family videos because of their impact on the entertainment industry.
I certainly disagree with the effect of the Raich decision. But, I believe there was a previous Supreme Court decision on which Raich was based. It had to do with a farmer who grew wheat for his own consumption in excess of his allotment of acreage to grow it. The Dept. of Ag caught him at it and sanctioned him in some way. The farmer said the wheat he grew for his own use did not enter into interstate commerce thus exempting him from the allotment’s limits in regard to wheat he grew for himself.
Court held in favor of Dept of Ag, saying merely growing wheat was engaging in interstate commerce. They got there via the commerce and necessary and proper clauses. I think your home videos don’t affect interstate commerce but their content is of interest to federal/state law enforcement depending on what it is and what use you make of it. So, the video doesn’t have to have any impact on the entertainment industry to be subject to federal law. NancyO
If I were a Republican leader I would stop all the court proceedings and allow the Obama administration to continuing screwing up the implementation so badly that PPACA just melts down.
But I’m not…..
Krugman links to a paper referring to Kenneth Arrow’s analysis of markets and reports that medicine in the US exhibits all the faults that make medicine not a open or free market.
Interesting since this work was done 50 years ago, and Arrow was one of the new rages in economics when I was an under grad.
Can private concerns deliver a bridge, any better than national health outcomes?
One underlying issue is no one wants standards in national health outcomes.
Some men and children are not all that equal when it comes to pain and living.
If I choose to watch home videos I’ve made of my family instead re-runs of America’s Funniest Videos, the dialectical conclusion from Raich is that I’m impacting interstate commerce.
Right again, ilsm. NancyO
Just to clarify: I sent this post to Dan for posting on Tuesday, but he didn’t have a chance to post it until today. (It’s been up on my blog since Tuesday.) The appellate argument in the 11th Circuit was yesterday morning. (I was wrong about the time of day.)
Turns out I was on to something when I wrote in that post:
“[Joondelph’s] right, but only if, as he says earlier, the market for health insurance is defined so narrowly that health insurance is viewed as a commodity, a product, independent of the product’s purpose and effect. And then, the constitutional issue would not, I think, be whether Congress has the authority under the Commerce Clause, aided by the Necessary and Proper Clause, to regulate the health insurance market, but instead whether this violates some other constitutional limitation. You know: the slippery-slope-to-government-compelled-consumption-of-broccoli argument.”
Except that the constitutional issue will not be whether Congress has the authority under the Commerce Clause, aided by the Necessary and Proper Clause, to regulate the healthcare (rather than just the health insurance) market, but instead whether this violates some other constitutional limitation.
You know: the slippery-slope-to-government-compelled-consumption-of-broccoli argument.
That’s the basis on which the 11th Circuit, it’s clear from the oral argument yesterday, will decide the case. And it will be the basis on which the Supreme Court will decide the case, I think.
I’ll send Dan a post on this tomorrow. I didn’t have a chance to draft it today. But in sum: Ultimately the outcome of the ACA litigation will turn, I think, on whether a majority of the Supreme Court thinks it infringes more on personal liberty to fund this country’s healthcare system partly by requiring individuals to buy health insurance from private insurers on the open market than it would by requiring them to help fund the healthcare system via a payroll tax (as with Medicare and Social Security) or an income tax surcharge. I don’t see why it would. But then, I’m not Justice Kennedy, so my view doesn’t matter.
It is truley amzing how the Rpeublicans keep opening doors for Obama to step thru, and attempt to ease the pain of his ridiculous Presidency.
“then what Congress is regulating is a market (healthcare services) in which virtually every American activelyparticipates”
This is such a silly argument… How can one without complete knowledge of ALL citizens at all points in time KNOW that all American’s “actively” participate in ANYTHING… much less healthcare services?
This is exactly the problem with this law. You can’t establish with certainty that activity/inactivity is regulatable by congress by either the Commerce or Neccessary and Proper Clauses. You can’t get there…
Which is why Congress (if they had used half a brain) should have resolved this through a Health Tax and paid for everyones health insurance, insurance which would have paid for the desired healthcare services.
Congress has power to tax
Congress has power to say how taxes are spent
Problem solved. The nimrods just tried to get too cute for votes and killed the deal.
This ultimately runs right up against the “all powers not ennumerated here are given to the states or the people” text in the costitution – The idea of this is to say that the Constitution does indeed establish limited powers for government, limits that exist because if powers were elastic under “Commerce / Neccessary and Proper” arguments then… there would be no need to say “powers not ennumerated are given to states and people”.
Obviously the founding fathers were up on the idea that you can expand government power infinitely given enough lawyer time.
Angry:
You pay taxes don’t you??? You will declare your insurance either as a prepaid deduction from your employer, as a deducion, or as a tax. In any case, you will make a decision mentally to participate or not.
eople, what do we make of this extract of the SCOTUS transcript on Day 1:
CHIEF JUSTICE ROBERTS: The whole point -the whole point of the suit is to prevent the collection of penalties.
MR. KATSAS: Of taxes, Mr. Chief Justice.
CHIEF JUSTICE ROBERTS: Well prevent of the collection of taxes. But the idea that the mandate is something separate from whether you want to call it a penalty or tax just doesn’t seem to make much sense.
MR. KATSAS: It’s entirely separate, and let me explain to you why.
CHIEF JUSTICE ROBERTS: It’s a command. A mandate is a command. If there is nothing behind the command. It’s sort of well what happens if you don’t
file the mandate? And the answer is nothing. It seems very artificial to separate the punishment from the crime.
MR. KATSAS: I’m not sure the answer is nothing, but even assuming it were nothing, it seems to me there is a difference between what the law requires and what enforcement consequences happen to you. This statute was very deliberately written to separate mandate from penalty in several different ways.
They are put in separate sections. The mandate is described as a “legal requirement” no fewer than 20 times, three times in the operative text and 17 times in the findings. It’s imposed through use of a mandatory verb “shall.” The requirement is very well defined in the statute, so it can’t be sloughed off as a general exhortation, and it’s backed up by a penalty. . . .
CHIEF JUSTICE ROBERTS: Why would you have a requirement that is completely toothless? You know, buy insurance or else. Or else what? Or else nothing.
MR. KATSAS: Because Congress reasonably could think that at least some people will follow the law precisely because it is the law.
WILL THE SCOTUS RULE AGAINST C.J ROBERT’S VIEW THAT MANDATE IS NOT (REALLY) A MANDATE? IF THE CHIEF JUSTICE’S VIEW IS CORRECT, WHAT WAS THE CHALLENGE TO THE MANDATE ON DAY 2 ALL ABOUT?
People, what do we make of this extract of the SCOTUS transcript on Day 1:
CHIEF JUSTICE ROBERTS: The whole point -the whole point of the suit is to prevent the collection of penalties.
MR. KATSAS: Of taxes, Mr. Chief Justice.
CHIEF JUSTICE ROBERTS: Well prevent of the collection of taxes. But the idea that the mandate is something separate from whether you want to call it a penalty or tax just doesn’t seem to make much sense.
MR. KATSAS: It’s entirely separate, and let me explain to you why.
CHIEF JUSTICE ROBERTS: It’s a command. A mandate is a command. If there is nothing behind the command. It’s sort of well what happens if you don’t
file the mandate? And the answer is nothing. It seems very artificial to separate the punishment from the crime.
MR. KATSAS: I’m not sure the answer is nothing, but even assuming it were nothing, it seems to me there is a difference between what the law requires and what enforcement consequences happen to you. This statute was very deliberately written to separate mandate from penalty in several different ways.
They are put in separate sections. The mandate is described as a “legal requirement” no fewer than 20 times, three times in the operative text and 17 times in the findings. It’s imposed through use of a mandatory verb “shall.” The requirement is very well defined in the statute, so it can’t be sloughed off as a general exhortation, and it’s backed up by a penalty. . . .
CHIEF JUSTICE ROBERTS: Why would you have a requirement that is completely toothless? You know, buy insurance or else. Or else what? Or else nothing.
MR. KATSAS: Because Congress reasonably could think that at least some people will follow the law precisely because it is the law.
WILL THE SCOTUS RULE AGAINST C.J ROBERT’S VIEW THAT MANDATE IS NOT (REALLY) A MANDATE? IF THE CHIEF JUSTICE’S VIEW IS CORRECT, WHAT WAS THE CHALLENGE TO THE MANDATE ON DAY 2 ALL ABOUT?