Wage Inflation and Expected Price Inflation

Yesterday, I noted that an expectations un-augmented Phillips curve fits data from the past two decades rather well. Here is an even simpler illustration of the point that lagged price inflation has not correlated with wage inflation for the past two decades.

winlivingston

The figure is a scatter of lgwinfl — the percent annual rate of increase of
Business Sector: Compensation Per Hour (HCOMPBS), Index 2009=100, Semiannual, Seasonally Adjusted from FRED on pcecinf the lagged annual percent rate of JCXFE “Personal Consumption Expenditures: Chain-type Price Index Less Food and Energy (JCXFE), Index 2009=100, Semiannual, Seasonally Adjusted.”

Note that the data are of semiannual frequency, so each raw data point from FRED affects two overlapping intervals and therefore two dots on the graph. I look at data for intervals starting from the second half of 1992 through the second half of 2012 (the most recent available). The labels refer to the start of the intervals.

There is no sign of an effect of lagged price inflation on wage inflation. As noted by Nick Rowe in comments, this is what one might expect if the Fed were successfully targeting inflation. In that case the best estimate of future price inflation would be the target no matter what inflation had recently been. (Actually now that I think about it, current new Keynesian models still suggest a correalation as sticky wages catch up with other than expected price growth. But that’s not the point of this post.)

This is what central bankers and other people mean when they say that inflation expectations are anchored — they mean changes in price inflation don’t persist, because they don’t feed over into wages. However, anchored expectations can also be a statement about expectations. A lack of feedback to wages might be due to something else — Krugman argues that it can occur if there is downward nominal wage rigidity.

I have noted that lagged inflation is correlated with the breakeven inflation rates which would make the return on Treasury Inflation Protected Securities (TIPS) equal to the return on ordinary nominal Treasury Securities. This post looks at 5 year breakevens which should reflect expected inflation over the next five years. Bond traders’ expectations sure don’t seem to be anchored.

Surveys of people believed to be expert are another source of data. I have been playing with the Livingston Expectations urvey. This is a semi-annual survey of forecasts of many variables including the consumer price index. The base year index level is included in the publicly available data set, so it is possible to calculate forecasts for inflation over intervals. Again I look at 12 month intervals (so intervals overlap). The format of the Livinston Survey was changed for 2004. I use data only from the old version. My excuse is that I am keeping the new data (which are publicly available in files with a different format) for out of sample forecasting with no risk of data snooping. The real reason is that I am lazy.

Here is the scatter of the median Livinston CPI inflation forecast for CPI inflation over the following and PCECINF

wagelivingston2

Expectations sure don’t look anchored. Expected CPI inflation seems to increase about one for one with lagged core PCE deflator inflation.

Finally, I cut out the middleman. Here are hourly compensation growth and expected CPI inflation for the same intervals.

wagelivingston3

There is plenty of variation in the median Livinston Survey forecast of inflation, but there is no sign of correlation with wage inflation.

It remains possible that the expectations of people who set wages are anchored. Bond traders and Livingston survey participants don’t set most wages. Managers and other employees of the same firms bargain over wages somehow.